Assumptions
- ass. Investments are equal to savings, i.e. all savings are invested.
- ass.
Intertemporal Utility Maximization
ass. Households perform intertemporal utility maximization. Similar to Utility Maximization but according to the following general form of intertemporal utility maximization:
The equality is the intertemporal budget constraint that holds from . Limit the time horizon to just two periods, and . Then:
- Capital stock is initially
- No savings at second (=last) period Then the two constraints:
- Equating for we get:
This is the intertemporal budget constraint. Now solving for the maximization problem for the above Cobb-Douglas Utility function to get Unconstrained Maximization:
we get the first order condition (by optimizing the log of the utility function and getting first derivative):
where
Capital Accumulation
ass. Capital stock is acculated and depreciated via the following equation:
Then consider where is the savings rate. Then
thm. Capital Accumulation in intensive form (=per person):
- i.e. capital intensity, in
- i.e. population growth rate
- is the individual production function, i.e. per worker ()
- works because of assumption of constant returns to scale:
Implications
- Capital accumulation cannot explain per capital GDP growth
- …due to diminishing in
- Explains why per capita GDP converges to a certain point (intersection point in right graph)
- Expalins why total GDP grows as population increases, but also that population growth does not cause per capital GDP growth
Steady State Capital
We consider the steady state point, the intersection point in the right graph. We assume:
- i.e. capital growth rate
- i.e. Cobb-Douglas production function
At steady state . Thus: